Sunday 28 October 2012

The Proposed New York City Cigarette Tax Increase



The Proposed New York City Cigarette Tax Increase

Summary of main article

Under a proposal by Mayor Michael Bloomberg (pic), the New York City cigarette excise tax will rise from 8¢ per pack to a $1.50 per pack – an astounding 1,775% increase.  Coupled with the state tax of $1.50 (effective April 3, 2002), NYC consumers would face state and city taxes of $3.00 a pack. The City tax would be 3 times as large as the average state tax and approximately 5 times as high as any municipal tax in the country. NYC prices would be nearly $6.80 per pack, making a pack of cigarettes about 50% more expensive than an ounce of silver. The typical NYC smoker would pay roughly $1,400 per year in NYC and NY State cigarette taxes.

Does increasing taxes for cigarettes affect both cigarettes sellers and buyers? What are taxes actually? These are some of the frequent questions that arise among us about taxes. First of all, let’s get to know the definition of tax. Tax is a pecuniary burden laid upon individuals or property owners to support the government. It is to impose a financial charge or other levy upon a taxpayer. When the government imposes a tax on the sale of a good, in this case – cigarettes; the price paid by buyers might rise by the full amount of the tax, by a lesser amount, or not at all. For example, if the price paid by cigarettes buyers rises by the full amount of the tax, then the burden of the tax falls entirely on buyers. If the price paid by cigarettes buyers rises by a lesser amount than the tax, then the burden of the tax falls partly on buyers and partly on sellers of cigarettes. And if the price paid by cigarettes buyers doesn't change at all, then the burden of the tax falls entirely on the cigarettes sellers.

A Tax on Sellers
The effects of this tax causes on the sellers of cigarettes can be seen, on the demand and supply in the market for cigarettes. In the graph below, the demand curve is D, and the supply curve is S. With no tax, the equilibrium price is $3 per pack and 350 million packs a year are bought and sold. A tax on sellers is like an increase in cost, so it decreases supply. In order to determine the position of the new supply curve, we add the tax to the minimum price that sellers are willing to accept for each quantity sold. You can see that without the tax, sellers are willing to offer 350 million packs a year for $3 a pack. So with a $1.50 tax, they will offer 350 million packs a year only if the price is $4.50 a pack. The supply curve shift from S to S + tax on sellers.. Equilibrium (e) occurs when the new supply curve intersects the demand curve at 325 million packs a year. The prices paid by buyers rises by $1 to $4 a pack. And the price received by sellers falls by 50¢ to $2.50 a pack. So buyers pay $1 of the tax and sellers pay the other 50¢.




























A Tax on Buyers
A tax on buyers lowers the amount they are willing to pay sellers, so it decreases demand and shifts the demand curve leftward. To determine the position of this new demand curve, we need to subtract the tax from the maximum price that buyers are willing to pay for each quantity bought. As seen in the graph below, that without the tax, buyers are willing to buy 350 million packs a year for $3 a pack. So with a $1.50 tax, they are willing to buy 350 million packs a year only if the price including the tax is $3 a pack, which means that they’re willing to pay sellers only $1.50 a pack. The demand curve shift from D to D – tax on buyers. Equilibrium (e) occurs when the new demand curve intersects the supply curve at a quantity of 325 million packs a year. The price received by sellers is $2.50 a pack, and the price paid by buyers is $4.



Taxes and Fairness
The benefits principle is the proposition that people should pay taxes equal to the benefits they receive from the services provided by government. For example, CEO’s pays a higher tax to the government because of their positions at the high level of the corporate business world – higher income while construction workers pays considerably less tax since they earn considerably less.  Another example would be, according to the article, is that higher taxes would be imposed on cigarettes sellers who bought a large number of cigarettes packs than those who bought much smaller packs that to be sold. This arrangement is fair because it means that those who benefit most pay the most taxes. It makes tax payments and the consumption of government-provided services similar to private consumption expenditures. The ability-to-pay principle is the proposition that people should pay taxes according to how easily they can bear the burden of the tax. For example, a rich person can easily bear the burden than a poor person can, so the ability-to-pay principle can reinforce the benefits principle to justify high rates of income tax on high incomes.

Therefore, increasing the taxes on cigarettes actually affect both the cigarettes buyers and sellers. For instance, for cigarettes sellers, without the tax, they are willing to offer 350 million packs per year for $3 a pack. So with a $1.50 tax, cigarettes sellers are only willing to offer 350 million packs per year only if the price is $4.50 a pack. Meanwhile, for cigarettes buyers, without the tax, they are willing to buy 350 million packs per year for $3.00 a pack. So with a $1.50 tax, cigarettes buyers are only willing to buy 350 million packs a year only if the price including the tax is $3 a pack, which means that they’re willing to pay sellers only $1.50 a pack.  


No comments:

Post a Comment